Technological change in energy - MESSAGE-GLOBIOM: Difference between revisions
No edit summary |
m (Text replacement - "|HasLevel=2 " to "") |
||
Line 3: | Line 3: | ||
|IsDocumentationOf=MESSAGE-GLOBIOM | |IsDocumentationOf=MESSAGE-GLOBIOM | ||
|DocumentationCategory=Technological change in energy | |DocumentationCategory=Technological change in energy | ||
|HasSeq=5 | |HasSeq=5 | ||
|HasParent=Energy_-_MESSAGE-GLOBIOM | |HasParent=Energy_-_MESSAGE-GLOBIOM |
Revision as of 15:56, 23 June 2020
Corresponding documentation | |
---|---|
Previous versions | |
Model information | |
Model link | |
Institution | International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA), Austria, http://data.ene.iiasa.ac.at. |
Solution concept | General equilibrium (closed economy) |
Solution method | Optimization |
Anticipation |
Technological change in MESSAGE is generally treated exogenously, although pioneering work on the endogenization of technological change via learning curves in energy-engineering type models (Messner, 1997 MSG-GLB_messner_endogenized_1997) and the dependence of technology costs on market structure has been done with MESSAGE (Leibowicz, 2015 MSG-GLB_leibowicz_growth_2015). The current cost and performance parameters, including conversion efficiencies and emission coefficients is generally derived from the relevant engineering literature. For the future alternative cost and performance projections are developed to cover a relatively wide range of uncertainties that influences model results to a good extent.
Technology cost
The quantitative assumptions about technology cost development are derived from the overarching qualitative SSP narratives (cf. section narratives). In SSP1, for instance, whose green-growth storyline is more consistent with a sustainable development paradigm, higher rates of technological progress and learning are assumed for renewables and other advanced technologies that may replace fossil fuels (e.g., the potential for electric mobility is assumed to be higher in SSP1 compared to SSP2 or SSP3). In contrast, SSP3 assumes limited progress across a host of advanced technologies, particularly for renewables and hydrogen; more optimistic assumptions are instead made for coal-based technologies, not only for power generation but also for liquid fuels production. Meanwhile, the middle-of-the-road SSP2 narrative is characterized by a fairly balanced view of progress for both conventional fossil and non-fossil technologies. In this sense, technological development in SSP2 is not biased toward any particular technology group.
Technological costs vary regionally in all SSPs, reflecting marked differences in engineering and construction costs across countries observed in the real world. Generally, costs start out lower in the developing world and are assumed to converge to those of present-day industrialized countries as the former becomes richer throughout the century (thus, the cost projections consider both labour and capital components). This catch-up in costs is assumed to be fastest in SSP1 and slowest in SSP3 (where differences remain, even in 2100); SSP2 is in between. Estimates for present-day and fully learned-out technology costs are from the Global Energy Assessment (Riahi et al., 2012 MSG-GLB_riahi_chapter_2012) and World Energy Outlook (IEA, 2014 MSG-GLB_international_energy_agency_world_2014). A summary of these cost assumptions can be found in sections Electricity of MESSAGE-GLOBIOM and Other conversion of MESSAGE-GLOBIOM.
Technology diffusion
MESSAGE tracks investments by vintage, an important feature to represent the inertia in the energy system due to its long-lived capital stock. In case of shocks (e.g., introduction of stringent climate policy), it is however possible to prematurely retire existing capital stock such as power plants or other energy conversion technologies and switch to more suitable alternatives.
An important factor in this context that influences technology adoption in MESSAGE are technology diffusion constraints. Technology diffusion in MESSAGE is determined by dynamic constraints that relate the construction of a technology added or the activity (level of production) of a technology in a period t to construction or the activity in the previous period t-1 (Messner and Strubegger, 1995 MSG-GLB_messner_users_1995 cf. section :ref:`upper_dynamic_constraint_capacity).
While limiting the possibility of flip-flop behavior as is frequently observed in unconstrained Linear Programming (LP) models such as MESSAGE, a drawback of such hard growth constraints is that the relative advantage of some technology over another technology is not taken into account and therefore even for very competitive technologies, no acceleration of technology diffusion is possible. In response to this limitation, so called flexible or soft dynamic constraints have been introduced into MESSAGE (Keppo and Strubegger, 2010 MSG-GLB_keppo_short_2010). These allow faster technology diffusion at additional costs and therefore generate additional model flexibility while still reducing the flip-flop behavior and sudden penetration of technologies.
<xr id="fig:MESSAGE-GLOBIOM_difconstraint"/> below illustrates the maximum technology growth starting at a level of 1 in year t=0 for a set of five diffusion constraints which jointly lead to a soft constraint.
For a more detailed description of the implementation of technology diffusion constraints, see the Annex Section ref:annex_convtech.